The Panic of 1907 (Book Excerpt)

Panic_of_1907_jacketTime for another book excerpt:

I previously mentioned The Panic of 1907: Lessons Learned from the Market’s Perfect Storm by Robert F. Bruner and Sean D. Carr, in a linkfest a few months ago.

I found the book, published exactly a century after the original event, to have some rather interesting parallels to today.

The significance of the 1907 Panic as an economic event went far beyond the mere crash and recovery.  It eventually led to the creation of the U.S. Federal Reserve.

There is a video excerpt from the book here.

The authors point out the following Déjà vu — 100 years later:  "War was fresh in mind. Immigration was fueling dramatic changes in society. New technologies were changing people’s everyday lives. Wall Street was wheeling and dealing . . ."

They also name 7 factors are required to develop a financial panic:  Buoyant Growth, Systemic Architecture, Inadequate Safety Buffers, Adverse Leadership, Real Economic Shock, Fear and Greed, Failure of Collective Action.

The Intro, and Chapters 1 -3 follow after the jump.

Enjoy!

>

Macro_trends_18851913

>

>

>

You can find the PDFs of the first few chapters at the end of this post. But first, the required legal disclaimer:

"Excerpted with permission of the publisher John Wiley & Sons, Inc. from The Panic of 1907: Lessons Learned from the Market’s Perfect Storm. Copyright (c) 2007 by Robert F. Bruner, Sean D. Carr. This book is available at all bookstores, online booksellers and from the Wiley web site at www.wiley.com, or call 1-800-225-5945. 

Here is the text excerpt for the book:

~~~

The Panic of 1907: Lessons Learned from the Market’s Perfect Storm

by Robert F. Bruner and Sean D. Carr

INTRODUCTION

Why do market crashes and banking panics happen? Conventional wisdom on this question has gathered, like iron filings, at two intellectual poles. At one extreme, we find explanations that are highly detailed and idiosyncratic to a particular event—often comprised of a hodge-podge of period-specific causes.

At the other extreme are conclusions that might be broadly described as “one big idea”: a sole cause large enough to cover a multitude of sins. A favorite big idea among some economists, for example, is that financial crises follow a lack of liquidity in the financial system. Another popular big-idea explanation is simple greed or venality.

Unfortunately, the one big idea often ignores the considerable richness of detail that the recounting of a single crisis can reveal, and thus produces simplistic conclusions and inappropriate recommendations for decision makers. One wants more, an explanation that is neither too much nor too little; neither too idiosyncratic nor too simplistic. Therefore, by drawing on a detailed history of the crash and panic of 1907 and on an extensive body of research about financial crises, we offer an alternative view that is as applicable to the past as to the future.

From 1814 to 1914, the United States saw 13 banking panics—of these, the panic of 1907 was among the worst.2 The panic had coincided with a series of major market downturns, culminating in a 37 percent decline in the value of all listed stocks. Triggered by the literal and figurative shock of a massive earthquake and a rash of fires that destroyed the city of San Francisco in 1906, the financial crisis of 1907 had global implications, and it called forth the leadership of a small group of powerful financiers. Though the duration of the crisis was relatively brief, the repercussions proved far-reaching, resulting in the formal establishment of a powerful central bank in the United States through the Federal Reserve System.

To understand fully the crash and panic of 1907, one must consider its context. A Republican moralist was in the White House. War was fresh in mind. Immigration was fueling dramatic changes in society. New technologies were changing people’s everyday lives. Business consolidators and their Wall Street advisers were creating large, new combinations through mergers and acquisitions, while the government was investigating and prosecuting prominent executives—led by an aggressive young prosecutor from New York. The public’s attitude toward business leaders, fueled by a muckraking press, was largely negative. The government itself was becoming increasingly interventionist in society and, in some ways, more intrusive in individual life. Much of this was stimulated by a postwar economic expansion that, with brief interruptions, had lasted about 50 years. Bring, then, a sense of irony informed by the present to an understanding of 1907.

Stock market crashes and banking panics had surfaced periodically in the United States and elsewhere throughout the nineteenth century. Market crashes often sprang from occasional bubbles in asset prices: extreme speculations in land and new securities would “correct” when investors’ expectations failed to be realized.3 Banking panics were often the consequence of these corrections as adjustments in asset valuations sent shock waves through the young country’s financial system. The nation’s banks, realizing that the value of pledged collateral had impaired the creditworthiness of their loans, would call in their credits. Borrowers, unable to repay their debts, would default and declare bankruptcy. Consequently, nervous bank depositors would fear for the survival of the bank and rush to withdraw their funds. If one institution failed in the process, then a panic would spread—a classic “run on the banks.” Unlike France, Germany, and Britain, the United States lacked a central banking authority that could supply extra liquidity in such times of credit anorexia.

By 1907, economic growth in America had lifted business expectations; a cataclysmic disaster in California would shatter them. How the effects of an external shock to the economy would wend their way into violent price changes a year later tells a story of how complex systems process information. The markets for stocks, debt, currency, gold, copper, and other commodities form such a complex system—they are interrelated in the sense that fundamental changes in one can affect prices in the others. Common factors such as inflation, real economic growth, liquidity, and external shocks can affect them all. How we make meaning of crashes and panics, then, is fundamentally a question of information its content, how it is gathered, and how the complex system of the markets distills it into security prices.

Over the years the occurrence of large and systemic financial crises has been the focus of considerable research—both directly and through varied intellectual streams: macroeconomics, game theory, group psychology, financial economics, complexity theory, the economics of information, and management theory. The following detailed account of the events of 1907 draws upon this rich literature to suggest that financial crises result from a convergence of forces, a “perfect storm”4 at work in the financial markets. Throughout the dramatic story of the panic of 1907, we explore this metaphor as we highlight seven elements of the market’s perfect storm:

1. System-like architecture. Complexity makes it difficult to know what is going on and establishes linkages that enable contagion of the crisis to spread.

2. Buoyant growth. Economic expansion creates rising demands for capital and liquidity and the excessive mistakes that eventually must be corrected.

3. Inadequate safety buffers. In the late stages of an economic expansion, borrowers and creditors overreach in their use of debt, lowering the margin of safety in the financial system.

4. Adverse leadership. Prominent people in the public and private spheres implement policies that raise uncertainty, which impairs confidence and elevates risk.

5. Real economic shock. Unexpected events hit the economy and financial system, causing a sudden reversal in the outlook of investors and depositors.

6. Undue fear, greed, and other behavioral aberrations. Beyond a change in the rational economic outlook is a shift from optimism to pessimism that creates a self-reinforcing downward spiral. The more bad news, the more behavior that generates bad news.

7. Failure of collective action. The best-intended responses by people on the scene prove inadequate to the challenge of the crisis.

This pluralistic approach affords a framework through which the alert observer can make sense of unfolding events; we invite reflection on their application to the crisis of 1907, and we return to them at length in the final chapter.

Interpreting and even anticipating future financial crises requires insights into the forces suggested here—not merely individually, but also collectively—how they interact to produce a crisis. This approach may lead us, perhaps, to a more complicated explanation of financial crises than pundits and politicians want to hear, yet the metaphor of the perfect storm reveals a possible outlook for decision makers—one
that suggests that the way to forestall a financial crisis is to anticipate the storm’s volatile elements and, perhaps, even to fight their potential convergence.

~~~

Chapter 1:  Wall Street Oligarchs

A man I do not trust could not get money from me on all the bonds in Christendom. 
—J. Pierpont Morgan

In 1907, the young American economy was roaring. Between the mid-1890s and the end of 1906, the nation’s annual growth rate was a stunning 7.3 percent, which had doubled the absolute size of all U.S. industrial production during a relatively brief period. The volatility of this growth also leaped from just over 6.5 percent to 8.0 percent per year—although, relative to the high rate of growth, this economic
volatility was slightly lower than what it had been during much of the nineteenth century. Even so, compared with previous periods of major industrial expansion, the U.S. economy in 1907 was larger and growing faster than ever (see Figure 1.1).

With the dramatic growth and economic development of the United States at the turn of the century came an enormous demand for capital. In 1895 the U.S. economy added $2.5 billion to its fixed plant and inventories, and by 1906 the annual rate of capital formation was running at nearly $5 billion, a blistering pace (see Figure 1.2). Much of this was financed by the country’s exports, which appeared as a bulging current account surplus after 1895. But even exports were insufficient to finance the very large growth rate in the formation of capital in 1905 (12.7%) and 1906 (21.8%).

Into this prodigious vacuum moved a tightly knit network of financiers in New York and London who possessed the sophistication and credibility to raise the necessary funds for America’s factories and infrastructure in the world’s capital markets. Their success in attracting foreign capital to America’s “emerging market” was reflected in the immense importations of gold in 1906:† the inflow of gold to the United States spiked sharply upward to $165 million, dwarfing all gold flows after the Civil War, except during the year of a significant economic downturn in 1893.

America’s rapid industrialization during this period also hastened the emergence of business entities of unprecedented scale, complexity, and power. Between 1894 and 1904, more than 1,800 companies were consolidated into just 93 corporations.3 Some of these large firms had grown by buying up smaller competitors during times of economic distress, while others were organized by financiers seeking to control competition and build efficiencies of scale. Much of the volume of new debt and equity financing for these large corporations again flowed through a relatively small circle of financial institutions in New York, including J. P. Morgan & Company; Kuhn, Loeb & Company; the First National Bank; the National City Bank; Kidder, Peabody & Company; and Lee, Higginson & Company.

In 1907, the informal but undisputed leader of this financial community in the United States was J. Pierpont Morgan, known to his family and friends simply as “Pierpont.” A complex man, biographers have found unusual clues to Morgan’s personality. Historian Vincent Carosso characterized him as a devoted family man, a “strong-willed, affectionate, protective, and generous paterfamilias.”

Biographer Jean Strouse divined that Morgan was estranged (but not divorced) from his wife, that he had amorous relations with other women, and at the same time was a prominent figure in the Episcopal church in New York City. Strouse also determined that Morgan suffered from periods of clinical depression—indeed, business and family letters are replete with open references to his bouts with the “blues.” But all biographers are agreed that Morgan was a forceful personality.

Historian William Harbaugh wrote of Morgan, “What a whale of a man! There seemed to radiate something that forced the complex of inferiority . . . upon all around him, in spite of themselves. The boldest man was likely to become timid under his piercing gaze. The most impudent or recalcitrant were ground to humility as he chewed truculently at his huge black cigar.” Morgan’s nickname in the street was “Jupiter,” suggesting godly power. Once he reputedly dismissed the threat of a government inquiry with a comment to President Theodore Roosevelt that, “If we have done anything wrong, send your man [the attorney general] to my man [one of Morgan’s lawyers] and they can fix it up.” J. P. Morgan operated within a circle of talented professionals and influential figures in the New York and European financial communities, and he demonstrated great faith in their collective abilities to “fix things up.” Biographer Frederick Lewis Allen described vividly Morgan’s attitude about the role of the Wall Street oligarchs, of which he was the most prominent:

Morgan seemed to feel that the business machinery of America should be honestly and decently managed by a few of the best people, people like his friends and associates. He liked combination, order, the efficiency of big business units; and he liked them to operate in a large, bold, forward-looking way. He disapproved of the speculative gangs who plunged in and out of the market, heedless of the properties they were toying with, as did the Standard Oil crowd. When he put his resources behind a company, he expected to stay with it; this, he felt, was how a gentleman behaved. His integrity was solid as a rock, and he said, “A man I do not trust could not get money from me on all the bonds in Christendom.” That Morgan was a mighty force for decent finance is unquestionable. But so also is the fact that he was a mighty force working toward the concentration into a few hands of authority over more and more of American business.

Two of the leading figures in Morgan’s circle were George F. Baker, president of First National Bank of New York, and James Stillman, president of NewYork’s National City Bank. Though Stillman and Baker were direct competitors of Morgan for securities underwritings, the three men commanded great mutual respect having worked together in business and on charitable boards. Morgan’s son once told a biographer, “Mr. Baker was closer to my father than any other man of affairs. They understood each other perfectly, worked in harmony, and there was never any need of written contracts between them.” Baker and Pierpont Morgan were indeed warm friends; they respected each other and shared similar views on business matters. With Stillman, the relationship was perhaps more distant: “[T]hey did not always see eye to eye,” wrote a biographer. “Their mutual attitude, however, was one of respect and a certain degree of friendship.”

Morgan’s preference for the consolidation of power was matched by a record of consistent leadership in times of crisis and advocacy on behalf of investors. In 1893 Morgan stepped into the breach to help President Grover Cleveland raise gold in Europe as a means of resolving the deepening liquidity crisis facing the country. He was instrumental in the consolidation and reorganization of failed companies, most importantly railroads that had over expanded prior to the depression of the mid-1890s. In the process, Morgan introduced firm discipline and an investor-oriented point of view. In one prominent exchange with a resistant railroad executive, J. P.Morgan, said, “Your railroad? Your railroad belongs to my clients.”

Morgan also sought actively to avoid what he viewed as “ruinous competition” by merging competitor firms to produce corporations whose names remain memorable a century later: American Telephone and Telegraph, International Harvester, American Tobacco, National Biscuit (Nabisco), to name a few. In 1901, Morgan played a central role in the formation of U.S. Steel, the largest corporation in America. Capitalized at a value of $1 billion dollars, U.S. Steel was twice the size of the entire budget of the U.S. government in 1907. Carosso thus described J. P. Morgan’s general approach to business consolidation:

Conservatism . . . stood at the center of Morgan’s general business views. If he had any fundamental, guiding business policy at all, it was to promote stability through responsible, competent, economical management, and to be aware of his obligations to an enterprise’s owners and bondholders. There was nothing he disliked more than unrestricted competition and aggressive expansionism, which he considered wasteful and destructive. Morgan believed in orderly industrial progress, and he endorsed policies aimed at promoting cooperation. Large enterprises, he affirmed, should adhere to the principle of community of interest, not the Spencerian doctrine of survival of the fittest.

Morgan was more than just a consolidator of existing businesses; he also played the role of venture capitalist. Not only were several Morgan partners investors in Thomas Edison’s company, but Drexel, Morgan (the precursor to J. P. Morgan & Company) also served as the depository for the cash of Edison’s firm, arranged loans for the company, facilitated foreign transactions, and helped to manage Thomas Edison’s private wealth. Morgan even helped Edison with mergers and acquisitions and underwrote the initial public offering for the Edison General Electric Company.

By 1906, J. Pierpont Morgan was disengaging slowly from the day today activities of his firm to attend to his passion for collecting art and literature, serving on boards of charitable institutions, and touring Europe. He relied heavily on his son, J. P. “Jack” Morgan Jr., to manage his firm’s daily affairs, as well as his “right-hand man,” George W. Perkins, a partner in J. P. Morgan & Company. On April 17, 1906, the aging Morgan turned 69 years old. By this time, he was unquestionably, according to one biographer, “the most powerful figure in the American world of business, if not the most powerful citizen of the United States. His authority was vague, but it was immense—and growing.”14 On the morning after his birthday, an historic catastrophe devastated the city of San Francisco, California, setting in motion a chain of events that would eventually call for all the power, wisdom, strength, and influence that Old Jupiter could muster.

~~~

Chapter 2:  Wall A Shock to the System

General affairs here are about as bad as they can be.
—J. P. “Jack” Morgan Jr. August 8, 1907

The earthquake that destroyed San Francisco in April 1906 was unprecedented in scale and scope. In the wake of the temblor itself, broken gas mains ignited massive fires throughout the city. Disruptions to municipal water lines prevented fire suppression, and San Francisco’s mostly wood-framed architecture only fueled the flames. The conflagration eventually engulfed the city, leveling over four square miles, or about half of San Francisco, such that most historical accounts speak of both the earthquake and the fire as the source of the city’s destruction. San Francisco’s damages were reported to range between $350 and $500 million, or 1.2 to 1.7 percent of the U.S. gross national product in 1906.

The strains from the catastrophe in California rippled instantly through the global financial system. At the time, San Francisco was the financial center of theWest and home to the western branch of the U.S. Mint, so anything that disrupted business in San Francisco threatened the entire western region economically.

On the New York and London stock exchanges, news of the quake led to an immediate sell-off in stocks and a significant drop in share prices. Economists Kerry Odell and Marc Weidenmier have estimated that the disaster led directly or indirectly to about a $1 billion (or a nearly 12.5 percent) decline in the total market value of New York Stock Exchange securities. Prices of railway stocks fell more than 15 percent, and those of insurance companies declined between 15 and 30 percent during the two weeks after the cataclysm.

Relief funds were drawn into the city from around the country and the world: England supplied $30 million; Germany, France, and the Netherlands collectively provided another $20 million. Such international effects of the earthquake were further amplified because many foreign insurers had provided San Francisco’s underwriting protection. What most severely hurt the insurance industry was that most people were insured against fire but not earthquakes. British insurance firms, for instance, had accounted for about half of the city’s fire insurance policies; after the quake, they faced losses of close to $50 million. In fact, several insurers were overwhelmed by the claims and could not meet their insurable obligations; Fireman’s Fund Insurance Company, for example, faced liabilities of $11.5 million, exceeding its total assets by $4.5 million.3 Consequently, some underwriters imposed lengthy delays in paying for damages, while others discounted their claims, insisting that any earthquake-related fire damage was not explicitly covered in their policies. The Hamburg-Bremen Insurance Company demanded a discount of 25 percent for all San Francisco claims. Only six companies fully honored their obligations

While some British insurers funded their payments by selling their holdings of American securities, others liquidated assets heavily in foreign markets. This liquidation prompted major shipments of gold from London to the United States—$30 million in April and another $35 million in September 1906, amounting to a 14 percent decline in Britain’s stock of gold—the largest outflow of gold from Britain between 1900 and 1913. Eventually, these outflows of gold created liquidity fears for the Bank of England.5 The declining liquidity of the London capital market sparked the spread of rumors in New York that British financial houses were in trouble and required support from the Bank of England.

At the time of the earthquake in the spring of 1906, the global market for capital was dominated by London. The British Empire was at its zenith, and London was the locus of immense flows of capital. Charged with the responsibility of maintaining liquidity for the Empire, the Bank of England—the “Old Lady of Threadneedle Street”—held reserves of gold with which to meet the liquidity demands of banks and trading partners. Keeping the British mills, factories, and shops supplied with goods from the commonwealth was a fundamental premise of England’s economic system.

In an attempt to stanch the depletion of the country’s gold supply, the Bank of England raised its benchmark interest rate from 3.5 to 4.0 percent. Fearing further demands for gold with the coming Egyptian cotton crop,6 the Bank raised its rate again on October 19, 1906, from 4.0 to 6.0 percent—the highest rate posted by the Bank of England since 1899.7 Central banks in France and Germany followed suit and sharply raised their interest rates as well.8 Panic had not yet set in, but telegrams flew across the Atlantic between the world’s leading financiers, reflecting a growing anxiety within the financial community about liquidity and the likely actions of the Bank of England.

In New York City, capital was becoming scarce, too, as its gold reserves also migrated to San Francisco. The timing of these relief shipments to the West Coast was particularly unfortunate since they coincided with the ordinary demands for funds induced by the U.S. agricultural cycle: The harvesting and shipment of crops required credit until the crops reached the consumer. As a result of the capital shortage, the price of money in New York grew dear, and other sectors of the American economy started to feel the pinch. By the winter of 1906–1907, severe credit shortage had set in.

On December 18, 1906, Jack Morgan, writing to his affiliate partners in London, offered stark language about these stringent credit conditions: “Things here are very uncomfortable owing to the tightness of money . . . we are likely to have a stiff money market for some time to come.” A few days later he wrote with a clarification: “There is plenty of money in the country everywhere except in New York, and the only really alarming thing about the situation appears to be a very undefined feeling that there is something wrong in New York. This feeling extending to the large centres in theWest has interfered with the natural flow of money to this centre to take advantage of the high rate.”11 As the year 1907 began, there was a deep sense of foreboding among the nation’s money men.

Complicating the capital scarcity problem was a bullmarket in stocks, which had been spurred by the buoyant economic growth of the American economy through 1905. A “mammoth bull movement,” in the words of one observer, was running its course on the New York Stock Exchange. Jack Morgan, under whose direct supervision J. Pierpont Morgan had left J. P. Morgan & Company, noted a speculative sentiment prevailing in the stock market:

For the first time in three years the public—with stocks at their present high prices—have begun to come in and buy heavily with the result that the so called market-leaders are no longer in charge, and that the stock market is running away in a fashion which I must say suggests to me possible trouble in the future although not in the immediate future.

Meanwhile, enormous new issues of securities, particularly by railway and industrial companies, placed further demands on the resources of the moneymarket. Henry Clews, a contemporaryWall Street authority, said, “Indeed, the year 1906 from beginning to end witnessed a continuation of those inordinately heavy demands for money from Wall Street and corporations, and these led to the disturbed monetary conditions.”

While the equity market was attracting popular attention, the debt markets (i.e., bonds and loans) overshadowed stocks in both volume and significance. During 1906, debt market conditions diverged sharply from equities:While stock prices rose, bond prices fell (and thus, interest rates increased). The price movement in the debt markets coincided with the increasing demand for credit driven by the continued real economic growth in the United States, the agricultural cycle that drew financing
to bring the bumper crop of 1906 to market, and the shock of the San Francisco earthquake. Alexander Dana Noyes, a leading observer of Wall Street, wrote in 1909, “Beginning about the middle of 1905, a strain on the whole world’s capital supply and credit facilities set in, which increased at so portentous a rate during the next two years that long before October, 1907, thoughtful men in many widely separated
markets were discussing, with serious apprehension, what was to be the result.

~~~


Chapter 3  The Silent Crash


The whole situation is most mysterious; undoubtedly many men who were very rich have become much poorer, but as there seems to be no one breaking, perhaps we shall get off with the fright only.

–J. P. Jack Morgan Jr.
March 14, 1907

By early 1907, it seemed that the steady progressive tightening of money, which had been accelerated by the massive capital demands of San Francisco’s earthquake, had precipitated a slow and steady decline in equity prices—considered by some contemporaries to be a “silent” crash in the U.S. financial markets. Between its peak in September 1906 and the end of February 1907, the index of all listed stocks fell 7.7 percent, a five-month change in value unremarkable in view of the long history of the market, but pertinent as the beginning of a trend. Indeed, on March 6, 1907, telegraph correspondence between Jack Morgan and his partner in J. P. Morgan & Company’s London affiliate, Teddy Grenfell, reflected the deepening anxiety between the world’s financial centers:

Grenfell: Can you give us any information and what is your opinion of the immediate future of your market?

Morgan: Do not get any information showing real trouble our market although of course continued liquidation must hurt some people and may do severe damage in places. From what I can make out do not think stocks are in weak hands. Shall be surprised if immediate future brings much more liquidation, although of course impossible form opinion.

In the coming days, Teddy and Jack exchanged more anxious telegrams about rumors of gold shipments. Grenfell thought that at the “first indication [of] considerable withdrawals of gold,” the Bank of England would raise its interest rate. He wondered whether the U.S. Treasury would relieve the situation by releasing gold from its vaults into the financial system. On March 13 Jack wired back that he could discover no intentions to ship gold from London this week, though there might be attempts to buy gold next week.

By mid-March the “silent” crash had become audible as equity prices turned decidedly and sharply for the worse. Declining over a series of days (March 9 to 13 and 23 to 26) rather than on a single day, the index of all listed stocks fell 9.8 percent. Especially damaged were shares in shipping (off 16.6 percent), mining (down 14.5 percent), steel and iron (down 14.8 percent), and street railways (off 13.8 percent). The Commercial and Financial Chronicle, the principal financial periodical at the time, observed, “The liquidation going on in Wall Street . . . is phenomenal. Stock sales . . . are among the high records in the Stock Exchange history.”

J. Pierpont Morgan was absent from New York during these disturbances in the market; he had sailed for Europe at midnight on March 13, the day of the sharp market break. There, Pierpont met old friends, toured the art markets for possible acquisitions for his collection, and
relaxed at various spas and villas. Meanwhile, Jack Morgan in New York grappled with the confusion and chaos in the financial system, writing in a letter to his partners in London on March 14:

Here we are, still alive in spite of the most unpleasant panic which we are going through. The whole trouble lies, in my mind, in the mystery of the conditions; no one seems to be in any trouble, there is money at a price for anyone who wants it, and in our loans, and in those of all the Banks I have talked to, there has been no trouble whatever of keeping the margins perfectly good, except the physical difficulty of getting the certificates round quickly enough. . . . I could not yesterday finish this letter owing to the panic and general trouble, there being so much to see to with Father and Perkins both away. Today, things seem to be so much quieter that I am in hopes that most of the trouble is over, certainly for the present. . . . The whole situation is most mysterious; undoubtedly many men who were very rich have become much poorer, but as there seems to be no one breaking, perhaps we shall get off with the fright only.

As the price declines continued during the next week, rumors of the failure of financial institutions began to circulate. The London partners of J. P. Morgan & Company cabled to Jack: “London Daily Telegraph today states that house of international prominence has been helped in New York. Is there any truth in this? Who is it? Do you expect much further liquidation?” Jack replied, “As far as we know there is no truth in rumor international house having been helped. Newspaper reports here is that various stock exchange houses in London are in difficulties. Cable any information you can obtain. Urgent liquidation seems to be pretty well done but as many parties heavily hit look for depressed markets for some time.”

Indeed, conditions remained unsettled as the unrest spread to other financial markets. On March 23, 1907, the Commercial and Financial Chronicle noted, “Lack of confidence [among investors] is never reflected more unerringly than in the money market; and the seriousness of the situation in that regard is shown in the inability of the railroads for over a year past to finance their new capital needs.”9 Both the municipalities of Philadelphia and St. Louis made bond offerings, and in neither case was the underwriting successful. “Money is commanding such high rates that it is impossible to float even gilt-edged securities at the low figures offered by Philadelphia and St. Louis,” the Chronicle reported.

Finally, during the week of March 25, cables between Morgan’s partners suggested that the worst was past. New York investors took courage from the announcement that the U.S. Treasury would deposit at least $12 million with national banks to ease the money situation. On March 29, 1907, Jack Morgan reflected on the change in mood to his London partners:

The two panics within the last ten days have given people a big scare, and the losses of course are frightful. The fact that no one has failed is more of the nature of a miracle than of ordinary business, but it simply shows, as far as I can see, that practically no one was overtrading. . . . My own belief, however, is that the panic is over, and the fact that the Treasury is putting out money rather fast and that that action has really been the cause of the restoration of confidence makes me feel that it was at bottom a money panic. Not a money panic such as we have heretofore had, but an apprehension that, in view of enormous calls being made upon huge stock issues during the next few months the market might be so far drained of money that those who were obliged to pay the calls would have difficulty in arranging to get the necessary fund. The whole thing has been an interesting experience, although an extremely painful one and I shall be greatly relieved when matters finally drift—as they seem to be doing—into a state of dullness and cheaper money. . . . From all this long screed you may see that I am tired but hopeful, hopeful because of the simple fact that there is a tremendous productive capacity in this country, and that this productive capacity has not been one whit reduced by the colic we have all been having.

Almost as suddenly as it had begun, there was a sense that the mounting crisis had been stopped. The source of optimism in the market was the prospect of Americans buying £4 million in gold in London for shipment to New York; the U.S. Secretary of the Treasury, George B. Cortelyou, also ordered that $15 million be placed on deposit with New York City banks, thus giving much-needed liquidity to the capital markets. The Commercial and Financial Chronicle concluded that this “made a material change on Tuesday in the financial sentiment, the panicky tendency being arrested and a general advance in stock values taking place.” Within a few weeks, the disturbance in the markets seemed to have subsided.

Reflecting the financial anxieties caused by the March crash in equity prices, call money interest rates had spiked upward during this period, but they subsided when the flush of cash and gold into the New York money markets produced lower interest rates and a modest recovery in equity prices (see Figure 3.1). On April 13, the Commercial and Financial Chronicle observed, “The monetary situation has reversed its character for call money, from abnormally high to abnormally low rates—the relief in New York communicating a like tendency elsewhere. This change has opened the stock market here to more venturesome buying, and consequently speculative operators have again been in evidence.”

While an optimistic mood may have returned, robust buying behavior had not. The Chronicle noted an eerie slackening of trading and persistently low stock prices, which suggested an absence of investors from the exchange. During April and May, the index of all stocks fell 3 percent, with large declines in shipping (down 12 percent), household goods (off 12 percent), machinery (off 10 percent), and copper (down 10 percent). On April 20, the Chronicle remained gloomy, saying, “no refuge from the old instability has been found. . . .A harsher and deeper economic irregularity is what the doctors have to deal with before real recovery will be under way.”

Business fundamentals also looked bleak. For the month of April, the value of claims in bankruptcy had grown 38 percent over the same month a year earlier, with the sharpest growth in the manufacturing sector. On May 2, Teddy Grenfell in London queried Jack Morgan in a telegram about the stock market and when the banks in San Francisco might reopen. Morgan replied, “Think further demand for gold is probable but impossible estimate amount. Stock market—believe decline largely speculative. Do not hear of any serious trouble any where though market vaguely apprehensive of difficulty arising largely from varied activities President USA.” For financiers and investors in 1907, the “varied activities President USA” were an overriding concern.

Despite his patrician mien and pedigree, President Theodore Roosevelt was masterful at giving voice to the nation’s popular will. By 1907, Americans had become increasingly disturbed by the tumultuous changes that had accompanied the country’s impressive industrial growth. They were worried about the number and type of immigrants entering the country; the size, noise, and frenzy of the nation’s large cities; the effectiveness of their elected representatives; the consequences of old age, illness, and injury on the job; the day-to-day hazards of urban life; and even the quality of their food and water. Yet most of all they reacted with alarm to the rise of big business and the corporate merger movement. Some Americans, calling themselves “progressives,” argued vociferously for the right of a community to protect itself against those who pursued their economic self-interest without concern for the common good. President Theodore Roosevelt became their most outspoken proponent.

Progressives especially looked at J. P. Morgan and Wall Street with fear, some of it well founded. Since the Civil War, the history of corporate finance had been punctuated by instances of looting and self-dealing by the financial promoters. It seemed that the very intimate engagement of financiers as both insiders and outside investors opened conflicts of interest against which the public would not be able to guard. Moreover, many of the combinations these investors organized resulted in oligopolies and monopolies that sacrificed the welfare of consumers for the benefit of investors. The sheer scale of the new corporate trusts raised concerns about the possible abuse of economic power to achieve political ends. Standard Oil, for instance, had the power to extract rebates from railroads for shipping their products that were not given to its competitors. Muckraking writers such as Sinclair Lewis famously focused attention on unsanitary conditions in meatpacking. Lincoln Steffens exposed unsafe compounds used in pharmaceuticals. In this context, the rather closed world of high corporation finance seemed highly suspicious.

President Theodore Roosevelt was the personification of this progressive movement, and he applied his executive power to challenge the influence of large corporations and to mediate between labor and capital. He was a pragmatist in a time of great political ferment, and he carefully navigated between opposing attitudes. Most relevant for the events of 1907 were his attitudes and policies toward large corporations. On the one hand, Roosevelt accepted industrialization and the large scale of firms that it brought.17 He believed that large corporations were here to stay, and that the stance of government should not be to eradicate the large firms, but rather to identify and eliminate the types of combinations that were dangerous. “I believe in corporations,” Roosevelt said early in his presidency. “They are indispensable instruments of our modern civilization; but I believe that they should be so supervised and so regulated that they shall act for the interest of the community as a whole.”

However, to deal with the perceived ills of large corporations, Roosevelt also implemented a policy of aggressive enforcement of the antitrust laws, mediation, and regulation. In 1902, for example, Roosevelt initiated a series of important antitrust actions, beginning with a suit against the Northern Securities Company, a railroad trust organized by J. P. Morgan, James J. Hill, John D. Rockefeller, and E. H. Harriman in 1901 just five weeks after Roosevelt took office. Two years later, the Supreme Court ordered the company dissolved. Roosevelt also filed suit against the unpopular “beef trust,” an action that the Court upheld in 1905. When states began filing state antitrust suits against Standard Oil between 1904 and 1907, Roosevelt directed the Justice Department to assume leadership of the campaign against the oil monopoly.19 By 1907, the Roosevelt administration had sued nearly 40 corporations under the Sherman Antitrust Act.

In that same spirit, Roosevelt revitalized the Interstate Commerce Commission, which had been created in 1887, by signing the Elkins Act of 1903 and the Hepburn Act of 1906, which gave the Commission the power to set maximum shipping rates for railroads. He also reenergized the presidency and asserted executive powers to protect particular social groups and supervise the economy in ways not seen since Reconstruction. In a Memorial Day speech at Indianapolis, President Theodore Roosevelt railed that the “predatory man of wealth” was the primary threat to private property in the United States:

One great problem that we have before us is to preserve the rights of property, and these can only be preserved if we remember that they are in less jeopardy from the Socialist and the Anarchist than from the predatory man of wealth. There can be no halt in the course we have deliberately elected to pursue, the policy of asserting the right of the nation, so far as it has the power, to supervise and control the business use of wealth, especially in the corporate form.

Progressive activism was reflected at the state level as well; various states passed legislation sharply limiting the prices railroads could charge passengers. Business analysts believed these prices yielded revenues below the costs necessary to provide the services, thus inducing downward pressures on stock prices. The Chronicle opined, “What is ailing the railroads and the stock market? . . . The underlying cause is the same as it was at the time of the collapse in March, the same, indeed, as it has been for about a year and a half, during all of which period a shrinkage in values has been in progress. Owing to the assaults of those high in authority and adverse legislation both by Congress and the State legislatures, confidence is almost completely gone. No one is willing to buy at what appear like ridiculously low prices because no one can tell what the future may bring forth.”

The initial judgment of knowledgeable observers was that the break in stock prices in March 1907 had been sparked by investor fears arising from the Roosevelt administration’s aggressive attitude toward railroads and industrial corporations. “For a year we have been foretelling this catastrophe, an assured result of the trials railroad property, railroad men and other large capitalists have been forced to suffer,” the Commercial and Financial Chronicle said, commenting on a newly launched investigation of E. H. Harriman’s Union Pacific railroad. “What has just taken place is not the final scene. Hereafter, if the irritant is continued, as we presume it will be, it will not be so exclusively securities and security-holders that will suffer; all sorts of industrial affairs are sure to get involved.” That irritant, of course, was the president of the United States.

 

PDFs:

INTRO.pdf

Chapter 1.pdf

Chapter 2.pdf

Chapter 3.pdf

Print Friendly, PDF & Email

What's been said:

Discussions found on the web:
  1. mitch commented on Nov 19

    No need to worry it’s not Dejavu all over again, the Cubs lost in the playoffs. We can wait another 100 years..

  2. mhm commented on Nov 19

    Can we have the panic of 2007 and be done with it? Too much wasted energy trying to salvage this sub-prime, level three junk. Let it sink.

  3. joe commented on Nov 19

    Damn it, BR. I just ordered Manias, Panics & Crashes, Against the Gods and Devil Takes the Hindmost. Now I’ve got to go out and get another book to remind me of what’s about to happen to the global economy. Thanks for nothing!

    (j/k, this books sounds really interesting. And since I’m for the elimination of the Federal Reserve, I’d like to learn more about the events that led to its creation)

  4. mhm commented on Nov 19

    Off topic but why HP uses non-GAAP numbers in their quarterly earnings? Isn’t that almost like a made up number, since it is not a Generally Accepted Accounting Principles?

  5. bob niederman commented on Nov 19

    deja vu? hell – in “figure 1.2” the GDP dropped by 1/8 for 1 or 2 years – how in the world will we get off that easy? We are totally screwed.

  6. Florida commented on Nov 19

    Advancing volume vs. declining volume numbers were downright nasty today.

  7. paul commented on Nov 19

    The Fed works great when real men like Volcker are apointed to run it.
    when politicians and Wall Street run it then look out below.

  8. muckdog commented on Nov 19

    The more things change, the more things stay the same.

    As it was in the day of Noah.

  9. David commented on Nov 19

    Barry,
    Who said the worst crime a country can do is decimation its dollar?

    Bernanke knows that the Panic of 1907 was started by the decimation of the dollar, it was purely a money panic.

    President Ronald Reagan once said, that a dollar should be worth a dollar, not 95 cents or $1.05, and only weak men and governments devaluate their currency.

    “Do not repent these things, for they are heavier Than all thy woes can stir. Therefore betake thee To nothing but despair.” William Shakespeare

  10. me commented on Nov 19

    I enjoyed the book.

  11. Estragon commented on Nov 19

    I’m not sure if this is what you mean by “rather interesting parallels to today”, but let’s review a few:

    Military – In the decades following civil war, the country was involved in a number of nasty little wars (eg. Spanish-American war), but was largely hemispheric (the Roosevelt collorary to the Munroe doctrine).

    Economic – Largely agrarian following the civil war, but more recently a rapidly growing and industrializing economy.

    Environmental – Urbanization and industrialization were increasingly viewed as despoiling living conditions.

    Monetary – In comparison with already industrialized partners, monetary and banking systems are unsophisticated, unrefined, and in some turmoil (eg. bimetal debate).

    Political – Growing unease with concentrated economic power leads to populist political involvement in the economy (trustbusting, controlled rail pricing, etc.).

    Trade – Growing trade surplus and reserves increasingly stressing trade partners in the industrialized world, growing competition for markets in finished goods.

    This describes the US of 1907, but not so much the US of 2007. The description above probably better describes China of 2007.

    Looking at parallels, the first four of the seven elements of the panic appear to be applicable to China. The last three (following a shock analogous to the 1906 earthquake) remain to be seen.

    One interesting point of departure in the analogy is the nature of reserves. In 1907, reserves were held in gold. In 2007, reserves are held in USD.

    The 1907 panic is called the “rich mans’ panic” because, although it no doubt caused much wailing and gnashing of teeth among the wealthy, it had little lasting affect on the economy more generally. Gold flowed out of England at an alarming rate, but the system self-corrected. Today, with USD based reserves and the US playing the role of 1907 England, the temptation to print reserves may prevail.

    Interesting times.

  12. Winston Munn commented on Nov 19

    “G. Edward Griffin explained it this way in his book, The Creature from Jekyll Island: ‘It is difficult for Americans to come to grips with the fact that their total money supply is backed by nothing but debt, and it is even more mind boggling to visualize that, if everyone paid back all that was borrowed, there would be no money left in existence.'”

    So how can you have a capitalist system when there is no capital but only debt?

  13. David commented on Nov 19

    Estragon is right. The Panic of 1907 was long known as the “banker’s panic” or, “Rich man’s panic”, and was regarded by many to be an engineered panic, designed to build support for fractional reserve banking and a US central bank.

    I’m short on knowledge about this period and the panic, but here’s a quick link as a reference to this idea.

    http://www.fee.org/publications/the-freeman/article.asp?aid=4968

  14. Stormrunner commented on Nov 19

    Winston

    did you see today Financial Sense article which makes the comparison between Capitalism and communism and for all practical purposes comes to the conclusion we have acheived communism here in the states.

    http://www.financialsense.com/Market/daily/monday.htm

    So, just who are these ‘Keynesians’ who seem to be such ardent proponents of unsound money, anyway?

    Well, let’s just say that they are not capitalists. As Dr. Paul points out,

    “Capitalism should not be condemned, since we haven’t had capitalism. A system of capitalism presumes sound money, not fiat money manipulated by a central bank. Capitalism cherishes voluntary contracts and interest rates that are determined by savings, not credit creation by a central bank. It’s not capitalism when the system is plagued with incomprehensible rules regarding mergers, acquisitions, and stock sales, along with wage controls, price controls, protectionism, corporate subsidies, international management of trade, complex and punishing corporate taxes, privileged government contracts to the military-industrial complex, and a foreign policy controlled by corporate interests and overseas investments. Add to this centralized federal mismanagement of farming, education, medicine, insurance, banking and welfare. This is not capitalism!”

    So, if we’re to believe Dr. Paul, it seems that ‘core’ to where we find ourselves economically speaking is unbridled credit creation [fiat currency] and fiat money’s chief advocate – Central Banking.

    But doesn’t Central Banking and Capitalism go hand-in-hand?

    The answer is a resounding no!!

    To wrap one’s mind around this fact, they need look no further than the words and thought of Edward Mandell House, chief advisor of President Woodrow Wilson from 1913 to 1921:

    House was a Marxist whose goal was to socialize the Untied States. In 1912, House wrote the book “Philip Dru: Administrator” in which he stated that he was working for “Socialism as dreamed of by Karl Marx.” In this book, House laid out a plan for the conquest of America, telling how both the Democratic and Republican Parties would be controlled, and be used as instruments in the creation of a socialistic government. And he asked for the establishment of a state-controlled central bank, which were both proposed in “The Communist Manifesto”. And it was in 1913, during the very first year of the House-dominated Wilson Administration, that both of these proposals became law. The Federal Reserve Act was passed, which brought into power a private central bank to create the money of the United States, taking this power away from the united States Congress. And the 16th Amendment to the United States Constitution, the graduated income tax as proposed by Karl Marx, was also ratified.

    You see folks, Central Banking is, and always has been, a key tenet of Communism — not Capitalism.

    This is reality.

    Now I ask you all; is it really any wonder that in a world increasingly dominated and controlled by the tentacles of Central Banking [i.e. the Federal Reserve] – that American jobs have been systematically outsourced, currency, institutions and Constitution debased, all seemingly to the benefit of a Communist country – China?

  15. Winston Munn commented on Nov 19

    Stormrunner,

    It appears the pirates have made us walk the plank – the fifth plank, that is.

    “5. ‘Centralization of credit in the hands of the State, by means of a national bank with State capital and an exclusive monopoly.’

    Communist Manifesto #5,
    Karl Marx & Fred. Engels”

  16. The Dirty Mac commented on Nov 19

    Stormrunner: That was a great post.

  17. SINGER commented on Nov 19

    that stormrunner post was ill….more EXCERPTS Barry…….

  18. MarkTX commented on Nov 19

    Stormrunner,

    IS RIGHT…….

    BANK OF AMERICA just robbed me…

    Someone wrote a BOA check to me, and I cashed it

    “meaning give me cash”

    $5 service charge off the top to get my money

    from BANK OF AMERICA

    NO SHIT $5 CHARGE to collect what they owe me!!!!!!!!!

    The Teller (she) said I should have a BOA account and

    THEY WOULD WAIVE THE CHARGE!!!!!!!!

    I TOLD HER THAT IS FRAUD!!!!!

    She smiled and kept giving me the

    “rest of the story”

    and asked if I wanted to open an account (3 times)!!!!!!!!

    I told her I would not want to treat any person that way and would never be associated with them (BOA)….

    She (WITH BIG SMILE) still ROBBED me of my $5

    and she (BOA) will always win.

    Now think……

    how many people are getting

    FU*KED by that… and do you really think

    CONgress (USA) cares??????

    She also finger printed me and made me put my ID… State Drivers L in their machine….

    ANY THOUGHTS??????

    We can complain….Is anyone listening?????

  19. stormrunner commented on Nov 19

    Thanks for the accolades,not my stuff,credit ROB KIRBY, just sharing the days treasures with something to compliment Winston’s remark. The whole article is a good read.

  20. Philippe commented on Nov 20

    Karl Marx is alleged to have said that at the end of the capitalist system all corporations will merge together, the Fed is owning the Banks and not the other way round.

  21. Florida commented on Nov 20

    I think I read Stormrunner’s post in a conspiracy theory tract about the Trilateral Commission, word for word.

  22. Cherry commented on Nov 20

    Central banking was around long before Marx.

    Why Marx’s junk gets so overvalued is beyond me. Marx took half of his science from the liberals themselves, yet, nobody seems to understand that.

  23. Cherry commented on Nov 20

    I should also add, the “income” tax, also already used by various “liberal”(aka “Free Market” capitalist regimes) countries way before Marx.

    Sorry Stormrunner, you intellectualizing your social group. “Dr. Paul” is a fraud FWIW as well, his ideas would lead to “Communism” just by evolution of the Merchant caste. He believes in the science of the Talmund. The evolution of Capitalism is towards centralization and monoply. Marx was more into Christianity as a science. Hence, why he looked to end “religion” but gave Jesus the man pats on the back. I think he should have just tried to build his model around the religion itself. Talk about starting a debate.

    My father told me, when a Communist and a Christian are staring at each other, it is like staring into a mirror, but everything is backwards to each other. How true he is.

  24. ken h commented on Nov 20

    I believe Estragon has the right idea. There is no way to compare this to the past. Changes in technology have created a “Global Industrialization”. Our country is far advanced and will now have to wait for other countries to catch up. A reversion to the mean. Seems the credit debacle could hasten this.

    As far as the Communism blather, gimme a break! I doubt that the Fed has any control of this roller coaster. They are screwed either way. If anybody has control it’s the large corporations and in the end the market will shake out their greed. It’s already happening.

    Mark, why should B of A just cash your check for free? I have a business and I certainly don’t give free service. As far as B of A goes,…I wouldn’t touch them with a ten foot pole,..but if that was the only bank or credit union in your area,…guess your screwed? Next time, get “someone” to give you cash!

  25. Tom C. commented on Nov 20

    Cherry- Marx was the anti-liberal. Comtemporary ‘liberalism’ has it’s roots, as does marxism, in ‘scientific rationalism’. Contemporary ‘liberalism’ or ‘progressivism’ is rooted in the same quagmire of contrdictory thought. Collectivism = statism. Classical liberalism was the idea behind the US constitution. Limited government with defined powers creating a federal republic of law versus the ‘Democracy’ sought today by progressives WAS the ‘liberalism’ of old. Modern liberalism has become statism where the power of the central state has no limit since it is thought to be the repository of power reflecting the ‘general will’ since whatever the abstract ‘general will’ wants, it gets. the Federal Reserve was a creature of America’s progressive era whose ‘reforms’ were fixed in granite by the First World War. Marxism has largely been discredited although American progressivism still calls the tune.

  26. Stormrunner commented on Nov 20

    >> I doubt that the Fed has any control of this roller coaster. They are screwed either way. If anybody has control it’s the large corporations.

    I noted twice once in the original post and again after that these were not my words just and interesting hypothesis. Many, many times I have stated that I believe we have evolved into a trend toward Corporate Fascism, we live in a Plutocracy

    http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Plutocracy

    In a plutocracy, power and opportunity are centralized within the affluent social class.

    In communism dictators are chosen by military coup.

    http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Communism

    Karl Marx held that society could not be transformed from the capitalist mode of production to the advanced communist mode of production all at once, but required a transitional period which Marx described as the revolutionary dictatorship of the proletariat, the first stage of communism.

    From the vantage of my conspiratorial or tin hat mind as has been suggested, in either case the people are subjugated. It matters not how the dictators managed to seat themselves. The Debt-Based Fiat Fractional Reserve Monetary Banking system is the tool, repeat a tool not the control, whose usury finances the over throw of Democracy, these Republicrats we vote for are simply the financed prospects of this subverted system. This banking dilemma we now face is no accident. The fallout from the debacle will be used to lobby for and further advance initiatives favorable to the Globalist agenda in which the elite extend their advantage.

    As for the checking issue MarkTx is absolutely right. A bank should not be allowed to charge a fee to cash drafts written against a demand deposit of its own bank. This forces people into the system, the banking system, or they are required to insist on payment in cash, the account holder is already being charged for this service. What happens if the check was only written for five dollars.

  27. flash91 commented on Nov 20

    “Mark, why should B of A just cash your check for free? I have a business and I certainly don’t give free service.”

    BofA charged $5 to cash a check from a BofA client?
    I have had tellers tell me that from other banks, I just point out to them that the check writer is the customer, and they back right off.

    It’s not asking for something for free, it’s asking the bank to provide the service paid for.

  28. Mergers & Acquisitions Articles commented on Jan 25

    Management articles like mergers & acquisitions articles, customer satisfaction articles, human resources management articles, customer relationship management, writing reports articles are provided by Management-talk in India and USA.

  29. Mergers & Acquisitions Articles commented on Jan 25

    Management articles like mergers & acquisitions articles, customer satisfaction articles, human resources management articles, customer relationship management, writing reports articles are provided by Management-talk in India and USA.

  30. Mergers & Acquisitions Articles commented on Jan 25

    Management articles like mergers & acquisitions articles, customer satisfaction articles, human resources management articles, customer relationship management, writing reports articles are provided by Management-talk in India and USA.

  31. Mergers & Acquisitions Articles commented on Jan 25

    Management articles like mergers & acquisitions articles, customer satisfaction articles, human resources management articles, customer relationship management, writing reports articles are provided by Management-talk in India and USA.

  32. Mergers & Acquisitions Articles commented on Jan 25

    Management articles like mergers & acquisitions articles, customer satisfaction articles, human resources management articles, customer relationship management, writing reports articles are provided by Management-talk in India and USA.

Posted Under