Gates, Fees, and Preemptive Runs
Marco Cipriani, Antoine Martin, Patrick McCabe, and Bruno M. Parigi
Liberty Street Economics, August 18, 2014

 

 

 

In the academic literature on banks, “suspension of convertibility”—that is, preventing the exchange of deposits at par for cash—has traditionally been seen as a potential means of preventing economically damaging bank runs. In this post, however, we show that giving a financial intermediary (FI) the option to suspend convertibility may ultimately increase the risk of runs by causing preemptive runs. That is, investors who face potential restrictions on their future access to cash may run when they anticipate that such restrictions may be imposed.

This insight is relevant for policymaking in today’s financial system. For example, in July 2014, the Securities and Exchange Commission adopted rules that are intended to reduce the likelihood of runs on money market funds (MMFs) by giving the funds’ boards the option to halt (or “gate”) redemptions or to charge fees for redemptions when liquidity runs short, actions analogous to suspending the convertibility of deposits into cash at par. Our results show that the option to suspend convertibility has important drawbacks: A bank, MMF, or other FI with the option to suspend convertibility may become more fragile and vulnerable to runs. In other words, we show that instead of offering a solution, policies relying on gates and fees can be part of the problem.

Preemptive Runs
To formalize the intuition for why gates or fees may trigger runs, we consider a four-period model of the economy, as outlined in the exhibit below. Investors deposit money with the FI at date 0, for example, in the form of demand deposits that can be withdrawn at par or MMF shares redeemable at $1 each. The FI invests part of this money in a relatively illiquid asset—a bank might make a loan, while an MMF might purchase commercial paper—that matures at date 3. The FI’s investment offers a positive rate of return that the FI can pass along to investors who withdraw at date 3. However, if investors withdraw before date 3, the FI incurs a substantial cost in liquidating the investment.

A Three-Period Financial Economy

Consider what happens if uncertainty suddenly develops about the return on the FI’s investment. In particular, suppose that, at date 1, a portion of the FI’s investors—call them “informed”— learn that the FI’s investment returns are more volatile than originally thought. Let’s also assume that both the FI and the informed investors will learn at date 2 whether the FI’s investment has actually soured.

At date 1, the informed investors have a choice. They can immediately redeem to obtain their cash, which would force the FI into a costly liquidation of the investment. Alternatively, they can wait for the uncertainty to be resolved, since a favorable outcome for the FI’s investment will allow them to obtain a positive return at date 3.

For the FI and the economy as a whole, having investors wait is clearly better. This would avoid costly liquidation and allow for the possibility that the investment might turn out to be profitable, in which case everyone will be (ex post) better off waiting until date 3.

In fact, we show that under fairly general conditions, if the FI cannot suspend convertibility by imposing gates or fees on redemptions, informed investors will optimally decide not to run at date 1. Instead, they will wait until uncertainty is resolved at date 2, because waiting may allow them to partake of the positive return on the FI’s investment if it turns out to be profitable. After all, these investors would still have the option of redeeming at date 2 if they learn that the FI’s investment has turned out to be bad.

But what happens if the FI can impose a gate or fee at date 2? We show that if the FI’s investment turns out to be bad, the FI will exercise its option to impose gates or fees on investors at date 2. In this case, informed investors may obtain less than what they originally deposited with the FI, because they must share the loss with the FI’s other investors. This risk causes informed investors to run preemptively from the FI at date 1 in anticipation of the possibility that convertibility may be restricted at date 2.

Conclusions
We prove these points more formally in a recent Federal Reserve Bank of New York staff report. There, we use a traditional model of financial intermediation to demonstrate the basic proposition discussed in this post: Giving an FI the option to impose gates or fees may be destabilizing because the option itself can trigger damaging runs that otherwise would not have occurred. This result is likely to hold for a variety of adjustments to the assumptions in our model, because the intuition is stark: The possibility of a fee or any other measure that is costly enough to counter investors’ strong incentives to run amid a crisis will give investors a strong incentive to run preemptively to avoid such measures.

Even though our model does not address how runs on FIs can create large negative externalities for the financial system and the real economy, one important policy implication is clear: Giving FIs, such as MMFs, the option to restrict redemptions when liquidity falls short may threaten financial stability by setting up the possibility of preemptive runs.

Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.


Cipriani_marco
Marco Cipriani is a research officer in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Research and Statistics Group.

Martin_antoine
Antoine Martin is a vice president in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

Mccabe_patrick
Patrick McCabe is a senior economist in the Division of Research and Statistics at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Parigi_bruno
Bruno M. Parigi is a professor of economics at the University of Padua.

Category: Credit, Think Tank

Please use the comments to demonstrate your own ignorance, unfamiliarity with empirical data and lack of respect for scientific knowledge. Be sure to create straw men and argue against things I have neither said nor implied. If you could repeat previously discredited memes or steer the conversation into irrelevant, off topic discussions, it would be appreciated. Lastly, kindly forgo all civility in your discourse . . . you are, after all, anonymous.

One Response to “Gates, Fees, and Preemptive Runs”

  1. Frwip says:

    It’s really trying to see the SEC attempting to reinvent the wheel.

    Those SEC rules are trying to deal with the liquidity risk inherent to any financial institution engaging in maturity transformation .

    Well, guess what ? A financial institution that engages in maturity transformation is the very definition of a bank. If there is anything the history of banking since the Babylonians have taught us, it is that if it is a bank, if it borrows short term to lend long term and you want to avoid bank runs, it needs to be regulated like a bank, with capital requirements, actuarial requirements, restrictions on asset classes and quality, a central bank backstop, etc., etc., and so on and so forth.

    But, no. There are people at the SEC who believe they can reinvent banking and rewrite 5000 years of history with two feet of duct tape, a piece of string and a couple of regulations. Good Lord…

    Janet Yellen should simply step in and tell the SEC to buzz off. It’s the Fed’s turf, the very reason the Fed was created. The SEC has no business dealing in liquidity issues.

Leave a Reply

You must be logged in to post a comment.